Review of the Proposed School Fees Price
Controls in Uganda
Background
On 27th August, 2015, The Ugandan Daily
Monitor ran a headline article “We can’t stop high school fees - Govt”
and Uganda National Association of Private Schools (UNAPSI) took a depth review
of the proposed request from parents for Government to control school fees in
particular reference to private schools. Uganda’s government schools are often mistaken
to be the only option
for children from disadvantaged backgrounds. Private
school
enrollment has
been
increasing at
rates
comparable to
government schools
even after
the
government
started
implementing
its flagship program
of UPE and USE for universalizing
education.
The
percentage of children in the 6-14 years age group in rural Uganda
enrolled in private schools increased
(UBOS Education Report
2014). The figures for urban Uganda have
also increased. This is a clear indicator that parents prefer private schools, if they can
afford it. It may also be noted that the number of private schools which charge very low fees and
function in low income areas
have been identified to be on the increase, in response
to this demand.
The focus of private schools on English Speaking
and the significance of English in the social mobility aspirations of people is
one of the primary reasons that poor parents
prefer private schools.
But
this is only one
side of the story. As
the Education reports indicate, districts with higher enrollment in private schools also perform better in testing of learning outcomes. Most of these private schools in rural areas
and poorer sections of urban areas function
at costs much lesser than what the government allocates for its schools. Thus,
due to several such reasons the private schools in Uganda share
a huge
load of the education
sector and this is
without even considering
the smaller private schools
that are not recognized by
any education board.
While parents increasingly send their children to private schools, they are
also simultaneously
affected by the increasing cost of living every year. Private schools charge fees based on demand and this serves as a method of
eliminating competition to select students. This has created
a situation whereby the students from relatively better-off households
get preference over children from economically weaker sections for school
admissions. But since parents
want their children to be educated in a private school, but cannot afford it, they have sought the
help of the government to control the price
of
the
service offered
by
private schools. It is in this context, that some parents are requesting government to implement
laws to fix the
maximum
tuition fees that can
be charged by private schools. The economic and
subsequent social, effect of controlling
the price of education needs to be further explored, especially since
free government schools exist, which benefit from an increased education budget every year.
Regulation of Collection of Fees Act in Uganda
Uganda
does not have a Regulation of Collection of Fees Act in its constitution or by the
Government. The Act or Control would be understood as a reaction
to be expected from the government which has a history of ceding to public demand.
While complaints from parents and the media about some private schools charging exorbitant fees were cited as the reason for such a move, it
is
important to understand the unseen factors contributing to this problem. Under the Act, a district committee would decide the maximum fee that
can be charged
by a private school.
The factors to be taken into account under the Program to fix the fees charged
by schools, other than administrative costs and a “reasonable
surplus required for growth” are:
1. Locality
of
the
school, namely,
Rural area,
Town,
Municipality, District
Headquarters, Corporation
2. Strength of the students
3. Classes
of study, and
4. Status of the school, as indicated below:-
a. Schools having minimum infrastructure facilities as prescribed by the Government
from time to time
b. Schools
having infrastructure facilities more
than prescribed:-
i. Schools having more than minimum requirement of laboratory, more number of library books, classroom
facilities and other sanitary and
drinking water facilities
ii. Schools having more than adequate
classroom facilities, lab facilities, library
area, number of books, very good sanitation facilities, highly protected
drinking water facilities and other sanitary facilities
together with high percentage
of results
iii. Schools fully equipped with modern facilities like Air Conditioner with 100%
results
While schools may object to the fixed fee once, the ruling of the committee
would be optional and the
fee could be fixed for a
particular period of time. Schools may apply for a revision of fees after this time period.
The committee would
also have the power to verify whether schools that are already affiliated with the
Ministry of Education and Sports (MOES) charge fees commensurate with the facilities (Government Recommendations).
The law
would take into account the qualifications of teachers as an additional factor for the district-level
and/or any committee
that decide the fees for private
schools for a
three-year period. With
the Right to Education principle,
being implemented across Uganda
as a strong government initiative to universalize education, the private schools in the
country would be under much financial and administrative pressure to comply with the rules
as Education is considered as a Public Good.
The imposition of a maximum cap on the fees that can be charged
by private schools can
be an additional burden
that exacerbates the problem and Members of Private Associations are
protesting this
proposal.
Current Situation of Private Schools
Private
schools affiliated with the Ministry of Education and Sports (MOES) claim that most schools are already charging very low fees and the Control would mean that the fees would be charged at
a much lower level leading to a situation where they would have to be closed down.
The problems with the School Fee Regulation and
Control are manifold. First of
all, the complaints
against unreasonably high
fees charged by private schools
are relevant for only a small section of private schools. The vast majority of private schools charges
very little and
function in disadvantaged
areas, already bearing the weight of extra compliance costs. Secondly, government schools already exist in
all
these areas and people are
choosing to send their children to private schools instead. Therefore, the underlying problem is
that government schools are perceived to
be worse than private schools when it comes to
learning outcomes. But
rather than focusing on improving government schools,
the government is being tempted to make it tougher for private schools, which are already performing better, to function efficiently.
Thirdly, even if the
regulation of fees in private
schools can somehow be
justified, the task personnel formed to decide the fees have no representation from stakeholders
given the current practical situation of the private schools education sector. Bureaucrats, who are
in charge
of the
government school system or are part of it, will make
up the committees. And these committees are set up to be the monitoring system
for themselves, considering
that all complaints with the decisions of the committee are directed or redirected to the committee itself.
Price-control: Intended Effects & Actual Effects
The proposed imposition of fee regulation on private schools can be understood to be a
reaction to the demands of some parents against large private schools charging high fees for their services. This can also be seen as a direct result of the assumption that these are the only types of
private schools that exist, which is not the case. While consumers are always seeking lower
costs in any economy, the
problem with the government is that its attempts
to help the poor, it reduces costs at the expense of the producers. While this artificial reduction of price may be seen
as a positive impact by the consumers in the short-term, in the long-run the effects will be disastrous
for them as well. Producers,
who see no chance of increasing
prices end up having to cut costs, are unable to function efficiently and lose incentive to perform
better. The regulation of fees therefore has the unintended
consequence of lowering
the standards of private
schools, by destroying the competition
in the market.
The
regulation of price has always proved disastrous. It
is ironic that
though the intentions are always to protect the disadvantaged section of the population from being exploited, price
control often has the opposite effect.
Socio-economists
argue that when price is controlled
artificially in one sector (Fiona Scott), it leads to the talent and entrepreneurs in that sector to migrate towards others that benefit more. This is the case not just with setting the price at
a lower level than the market price, but for setting
it at a higher level as well. One of the problems with setting prices at a lower level is that it creates an entry barrier in the market, thus
leading to a shortage in the competition. In this case,
that would
mean fewer
entrepreneurs will be willing to start schools since it is not profitable. It is also the case that
existing schools will have to close down because they cannot meet running costs, and/or due
to a lack of demand
because
of falling quality as
a result of lower fixed
fees.
Scott also provides numerous instances in history where the control of prices led to problems
for the consumers, that it
was
actually supposed to solve. The
regulation of commodity price
in Paris in
1973 resulted in
producers reducing the quality of their
products and in the rise
of a parallel black market to provide services that
the legal
market
could not provide at
the fixed prices (Scott 2001). In the case of education, a parallel market would mean unrecognized
schools that cannot be
regulated by the government. Such schools
already exist because they cannot meet the infrastructure requirements that the government and education boards set down, and yet
they continue to
attract students. This should
surely serve as an indicator for the
results to be expected
from setting more regulations on private schools.
Another analogy is the example David Tarr gives, of
television sets in communist Poland. The government kept the prices of television sets artificially low, meaning that there were
fewer producers and they alone could not meet the demand generated
by the lower price. The
situation was such that the cost of regulation of
television sets to
Poland’s economy was ten times
the industry’s total sales (Tarr 2009). Both government and private schools
have maximum capacities, and
when the prices are lowered leading to fewer number of schools, this
means there will be more students out of school simply because there are not enough schools. In the Ugandan scenario, where more and more
parents are sending their children to private schools, the destruction of the private school ecosystem would mean that a large number of
students will be out of school because the government school system will not be able to accommodate such a large number
of students.
Thus,
while
the intention of fee regulation is
to decrease cost of education and therefore increase the access to education, the
effect is that it creates
a supply deficit which in
turn ends up reducing the access to education for the very population it had hoped to help. Drawing from
Tarr’s analysis of television sets in Poland, the logical result would be that the government
would have to spend
much more than it hopes
to, or is able to, on government schools, to
offset this supply deficit.
The
effect of price control
on a commodity,
as can be seen, will ultimately be
a costly form
of rationing of the commodity because
of the scarcity that artificial prices generate by making the market for the
commodity less attractive for potential
and existing investors.
The importance of education to a society is accepted
and education is now
seen as a necessary service. The attempts at increasing accessibility to these services, while justified, are misinformed. Schools
are expected to offer services without expecting profits, as is made obvious from international
practice that encourages schools to be registered as non-profit institutions. But the service offered comes
at a
cost and high levels of risk for the school management. With the imposition of the infrastructure requirements under the Right to Education principle, potential investors are likely to find opening schools to be an almost certain loss. Existing schools are
being threatened to close down
because they are not able to meet infrastructure requirements at the low
fees that they charge.
Price controls on top of this, will
make
this situation more severe
for the education market and ultimately, to
the accessibility of a service that is fundamental to the growth of any society.
Coping with Fee Regulation
The regulation of
school fees have been in effect in some countries and the associations
of private schools are still engaged
in seeking
legal recourse. While
there are obvious
difficulties of not being able to run schools with the same quality as before at lower costs, school owners also raise issue with the process of determination of fees. In some instances, the salary paid to teachers is not a factor in the calculation of fees. Several
schools which were
earlier offering annual hikes for teachers who gain experience change
and put it on hold as a part of cost cutting measures. Costs are increasing
every year and while most schools are struggling to survive
at the current level of
fixed fees, school owners are
unsure of whether they will be able
to run the schools in
the following years.
Private schools which offer extracurricular activities will either remove them or make them exclusive for students who pay
extra for them. This move may be challenged
in court to uphold the
right of schools to charge for extracurricular
activities
as long as they are optional for the students, as the regulation applied
only for admission and
tuition fees. School
owners also admit that
with the expected demand for admission increasing due to lower fixed fees, there will
be a larger cost involved in the
screening process as the
capacity of schools will be limited. The forced lowering of fees will
mean that the chances of
growth to accommodate
more students will also be negligible. It
will also increase costs for the schools while not giving them the opportunity to make up for these costs
by controlling the fees that can be charged.
Private school
owners in Uganda have an additional factor that has been in play.
According to MOES memos, reports and recommendations, private schools need to meet reasonable land requirements to be eligible for
renewal of recognition. However,
the cost of expansion may not be covered in the process of determination of fees by the district
committees, according to school owners and private school association representatives.
School owners suggest that most parents whose children are admitted in their schools understand the facilities that they provide and are willing
to pay the fees charged
but it is only a few
parents who have made it a political issue. The enforcing of different laws, together with this recent proposed move to regulate the fees, overlapping
simultaneously has created confusion for the schools on how to comply with all the regulations, and the government may make it a point not to
renew the recognition of existing schools that do not meet some requirement and to
identify the unrecognized schools to shut them down.
Conclusion
The regulation of fees collected by private schools would seem like a reasonable move
considering the mainstream understanding that all private schools charge high fees. But the problem
with the mainstream understanding is that there is a vast majority of private schools that charge low fees and cater to disadvantaged populations of Uganda.
What is also worth noting is
that more and more parents want to send their children to
private schools anyway
but the supply does not meet the demand. This is why
parents want the fees to be lowered. Private
schools generate demand due to a variety of reasons
from better learning outcomes, greater
accessibility and English medium instruction
to provision of extracurricular activities.
Consumers want the price to be lowered because there are not enough private schools and the existing ones
can charge higher fees and still attract enough demand. If, instead of taking measures to increase the supply of private schools and increase competition among
private schools so that
they lower the price by themselves to survive in the market, the government is being
requested to force the prices down, it will only lead to a larger supply deficit which ironically ends up further from the
consumer need that the supply should meet
their demand.
Once
this scenario is understood, the
regulation of
fees seems puzzling.
The
effects
of regulation
of fees are basically that
schools struggle to meet running
costs
and look for ways to cut
costs when they are already registered as non-profit
institutions or operate
as nonprofit institutions offering a public good. On top of this, there are other government regulations like the Right
to Education principles, across Uganda,
and the land requirement laws
that these private schools are
expected to meet for recognition. Thus, the not only are the extra costs not considered by the district committees
that may decide the fees to be charged by every school but the school are expected to meet several
government regulations
that they do not currently meet,
at the same time. This is in
sync
with the existing
government education policy that focuses on input
norms like infrastructure but ignore the learning outcomes
that schools produce. Private schools generate
demand from parents precisely because they meet their expectations of learning outcomes but the government continues to judge private schools
based on input norms. In this context, it
becomes fairly obvious that the private schools
would struggle to survive in an environment governed by a policy that
is
uninformed of the
causes and effects that occur in the education economy. The ever-increasing penetration of free
government schools is often the only primary premise
that drives policy.
No comments:
Post a Comment